2.9 Price Instability Problem
Where
open markets operate, the prices of goods and services are determined by
changes in their respective demand and supply. Money or currency is used to denominate
the prices of goods and services where the value of a currency is determined by
the quantity of goods and services that can be bought with a given sum of
money.
Increases
or decreases in the supply of money itself may cause a general increase or
decrease in the prices of goods and services irrespective of supply and demand
conditions within individual markets.
Michael
David Bordo argued that the adoption of the Gold Standard leads to price
instability in the short term and that this inhibits economic activity. At the
same time and perhaps paradoxically the Gold Standard is said by others to
cause deflation. However, when investigated empirically both assertions are
contestable.
Despite
the predominance of Fiat currencies in the world today, the first point to make
is that over the last 250 years or so, implementation of the Gold Standard has
been the norm rather then the exception. Since the beginning of the Industrial
Revolution to the start of World War I - in excess of 150 years - the classic
Gold Standard was implemented in the major economies of the world.
Looking
at the Britain ,
where the Industrial Revolution began and being the dominant world power in the
eighteen and nineteenth centuries, Table 1 above presents inflation in the UK since 1750
as recently published by the Office of National Statistics [3]. In these first
50 years, inflation averaged a steady 2% per annum.
Following
a deflationary period between 1801 and 1851 when inflation averaged -1.2% per
year, in the next 50 years prices rose by 0.3% per year followed by growth of
0.5% per annum to 1914 when the Gold Standard was abandoned in order to finance
the war effort. Average annual price inflation of about 1% over the period
1750- 1914 suggests the classic Gold Standard produced unprecedented long run
low price stability.
The
evidence on inflation for the UK
at least is clearly at odds with the argument that the Gold Standard causes
deflation. Between 1800 -1914, UK
prices were almost as likely to fall as to rise, when average annual inflation
was close to zero. Since this was often caused by an increased supply of goods
and services and not by a shortfall of demand, the resulting deflation was
benign. Prices tended to rise when many countries abandoned the Gold Standard,
during the First World War. As countries aimed to restore the Gold Standard at
the pre-war parity in 1925, prices were required to fall back - resulting in
policy induced deflation. This expectation of prices to fall helped contribute
to an environment with relatively flexible prices and nominal wages.
From
1925-1929, the falling prices and increasing output make this deflation to be
the likely consequence of beneficial developments reflecting the increased
ability of the economies to provide goods and services. Since WWII, there have
been few episodes of deflation worldwide, with UK experiencing an average
inflation of 7% since then.
Between
1999 -2005 an unwinding of inflated asset prices associated with a crisis in
the Japanese banking system prompted deflation in Japan , where consumer prices fell
by an average of 0.5% per year. The argument of short-term price instability
solely hinges on relatively high coefficient of variation ratios over the
period of the Gold Standard (as cited by Bordo). However the coefficient of
variation is a highly unstable statistic when the average (mean) of a dataset
is close to zero as was the case with relatively low and stable long term
inflation over the period of the Gold Standard. Thus the high coefficient of
variation shows spurious short-term variability over the period of the Gold
standard and is an unsuitable and improper measure of statistical variation.
Far from destabilizing
markets, short-term price variability around a low average in actual fact
suggests markets were providing effective signals for producers and consumers
to actively engage in economic activity during the period of the Gold Standard.
Indeed the unprecedented increase in industrial and agricultural output and
international trade during the Industrial Revolution suggests the
implementation of the Gold Standard had no apparent adverse or lasting impact
on the economy. This is shown by the 0.5% per annum growth in the UK ’s GDP per capital between 1750 and 1850 [4] - during
implementation of the Gold Standard - allowing for the increase in population
and inflation. Steady though unspectacular growth implies the Gold Standard had
no underlying adverse impact on economic activity. Economic activity rose ahead
with inflation and population increasing ‘average’ livelihoods, in spite of the
inherent disparities in income and wealth created by capitalism.
Looking
at the experience of Britain ,
this period between 1750 and 1914 of the implementation of the Gold Standard
can be contrasted with the following decades when the Gold Standard was
intermittently or partially implemented.
The Gold
Standard was abandoned between 1915-1925 and 1932-1945 with inflation in Britain rising
by 5.4% and 3.8% respectively. 1946 to 1971 saw the partial implementation of
the Gold Standard through the Bretton Woods system and inflation rose slightly
above 4% per year. Since the demise of Bretton Woods the UK ’s inflation
has been very variable exceeding 8% per annum between 1972 and 1993 with Fiat currencies
in operation.
The Gold
Standard anchors a currency to a relatively fixed monetary base guaranteeing
low inflation, with possible periods of low deflation. In contrast Fiat
currencies have a tendency to generate inflation – often at high growth rates -
even allowing for the mitigating effects of restrictive monetary and fiscal
policy.
0 comments:
Post a Comment